A simple model of copyright levies: implications for harmonization

Jin-Hyuk Kim1
1Department of Economics, University of Colorado at Boulder, Boulder, USA

Tóm tắt

Copyright levies are used as a way of compensating rightholders for the private use made of their protected works. This paper builds a simple model of copyright levies and investigates welfare implications of the harmonization of levy rates. The result is that, when the policy-maker places sufficient weight on the interests of collecting societies, harmonization could reduce social welfare. When countries are asymmetric, the country with a larger proportion of foreign consumption and more inefficient tax system loses more from harmonization. A calibration exercise using European data shows that harmonization would increase aggregate social welfare. However, in some countries, policy-makers are worse off although consumers are better off with harmonization. Especially, when larger countries have higher decision weights, the policy-makers are worse off overall, and hence would not agree to harmonize the levy rates.

Từ khóa


Tài liệu tham khảo

Akerlof, G., Arrow, K., Bresnahan, T., Buchanan, J., Coase, R., Cohen, L., Friedman, M., Green, J., Hahn, R., Hazlett, T., Hemphill, S., Litan, R., Noll, R., Schmalensee, R., Shavell, S., Varian, H., & Zeckhauser, R. (2002). Amicus Curiae brief in the case of Eldred v. Ashcroft (01-618), 537 U.S. 186.

Alcalá, F., & González-Maestre, M. (2010). Copying, superstars, and artistic creation. Information Economics and Policy, 22, 365–378.

Besen, S., & Kirby, S. (1989). Private copying, appropriability, and optimal copying royalties. Journal of Law and Economics, 32, 255–280.

Boldrin, M., & Levine, D. (2008). Against intellectual monopoly. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Boldrin, M., & Levine, D. (2009). Market size and intellectual property protection. International Economic Review, 50, 855–881.

Bucovetsky, S. (1991). Asymmetric tax competition. Journal of Urban Economics, 30, 167–181.

Casella, A. (1992). Participation in a currency union. American Economic Review, 82, 847–863.

Caves, R. (2002). Creative industries: contracts between art and commerce. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Chen, Y.-N., & Png, I. (2003). Information goods pricing and copyright enforcement: welfare analysis. Information Systems Research, 14, 107–123.

Delipalla, S. (1997). Commodity tax harmonisation and public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 63, 447–466.

European Commission (2008). Background document. Fair compensation for acts of private copying.

European Grouping of Societies of Authors and Composers (2008). Response to the second call for comments. Fair compensation for acts of private copying.

Ferreira, J. L. (2010). Compensation for private copying: an economic analysis of alternative models. Final report, IE Business School.

Gayer, A., & Shy, O. (2003). Copyright protection and hardware taxation. Information Economics and Policy, 15, 467–483.

Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review, 84, 833–850.

Hargreaves, I. (2011). Digital opportunity: a review of intellectual property and growth. London: Intellectual Property Office.

Huang, K.-W., & Png, I. (2010). Who makes the law? Political economy analysis and evidence from copyright levies. Manuscript, National University of Singapore.

Johnson, W. (1985). The economics of copying. Journal of Political Economy, 93, 158–174.

Khan, Z. (2004). Does copyright piracy pay? The effects of U.S. international copyright laws on the market for books, 1790–1920. NBER working paper #10271.

Kinokuni, H. (2005). Compensation for copying and bargaining. Information Economics and Policy, 17, 349–364.

Lahiria, S., & Raimondos-Møllerb, P. (1998). Public good provision and the welfare effects of indirect tax harmonisation. Journal of Public Economics, 67, 253–267.

Legros, P., & Ginsburgh, V. (2011). The economics of copyright levies on hardware. Manuscript, Université Libre de Bruxelles.

Liebowitz, S. (1985). Copying and indirect appropriability: photocopying of journals. Journal of Political Economy, 93, 945–957.

Lockwood, B. (1997). Can international commodity tax harmonisation be Pareto-improving when governments supply public goods? Journal of International Economics, 43, 387–408.

Mallinder, L. (2008). Electronics industry to continue subsidies of artists. European Voice, 21 February 2008. (Web. 13 March 2011.)

Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M., & Green, J. (1995). Microeconomic theory. New York: Oxford University Press.

Niemann, F. (2010). The online market: breaking the copyright levies deadlock. Ericsson Business Review, 30 April 2010. (Web. 13 March 2011.)

Niskanen, W. (1968). The peculiar economics of bureaucracy. American Economic Review, 58, 293–305.

Novos, I., & Waldman, M. (1984). The effects of increased copyright protection: an analytic approach. Journal of Political Economy, 92, 236–246.

Peitz, M., & Waelbroeck, P. (2006). Piracy of digital products: a critical review of the theoretical literature. Information Economics and Policy, 18, 449–476.

Png, I., & Wang, Q.-h. (2009). Copyright law and the supply of creative work: evidence from the movies. Manuscript, National University of Singapore.

Rogoff, K. (1985). Can international monetary policy cooperation be counterproductive? Journal of International Economics, 18, 199–217.

Scotchmer, S. (2004). The political economy of intellectual property treaties. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 20, 415–437.

Towse, R., Handke, C., & Stepan, P. (2008). The economics of copyright law: a stocktake of the literature. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 5, 1–22.

Wilson, J. (1991). Tax competition with interregional differences in factor endowments. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 21, 423–451.