When is intergroup herding beneficial?
Tài liệu tham khảo
Adolph, 2020
Alizamir, 2020, Warning against recurring risks: An information design approach, Manage. Sci., 66, 4612, 10.1287/mnsc.2019.3420
Bala, 1998, Learning from neighbours, Rev. Econom. Stud., 65, 595, 10.1111/1467-937X.00059
Banerjee, 1992, A simple model of herd behavior, Q. J. Econ., 107, 797, 10.2307/2118364
Betsch, 2020, Social and behavioral consequences of mask policies during the COVID-19 pandemic, Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci., 117, 21851, 10.1073/pnas.2011674117
Bikhchandani, 1992, A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural change as informational cascades, J. Polit. Econ., 100, 992, 10.1086/261849
Bikhchandani, 2000, Herd behavior in financial markets, IMF Staff Pap., 47, 279, 10.2307/3867650
Bird, 2020
Buttelmann, 2013, Selective imitation of in-group over out-group members in 14-month-old infants, Child Dev., 84, 422, 10.1111/j.1467-8624.2012.01860.x
Clark, 2008, Using the six principles of influence to increase student involvement in professional organizations: A relationship marketing approach, J. Adv. Mark. Educ., 12
Cramer, 2003
De Vries, 2013, The 24-item brief HEXACO inventory (BHI), J. Res. Personal., 47, 871, 10.1016/j.jrp.2013.09.003
Devenow, 1996, Rational herding in financial economics, Eur. Econ. Rev., 40, 603, 10.1016/0014-2921(95)00073-9
Druckman, 2020
Eikenberry, 2020, To mask or not to mask: Modeling the potential for face mask use by the general public to curtail the COVID-19 pandemic, Infect. Dis. Model., 5, 293
Ellison, 1993, Rules of thumb for social learning, J. Polit. Econ., 101, 612, 10.1086/261890
Ellison, 1995, Word-of-mouth communication and social learning, Q. J. Econ., 110, 93, 10.2307/2118512
Epley, 2006, The anchoring-and-adjustment heuristic: Why the adjustments are insufficient, Psychol. Sci., 17, 311, 10.1111/j.1467-9280.2006.01704.x
Farrell, 2012, The consequences of the internet for politics, Annu. Rev. Political Sci., 15, 35, 10.1146/annurev-polisci-030810-110815
Gadarian, 2021, Partisanship, health behavior, and policy attitudes in the early stages of the COVID-19 pandemic, PLoS One, 16, 10.1371/journal.pone.0249596
Gandhi, 2020, Masks do more than protect others during COVID-19: reducing the inoculum of SARS-CoV-2 to protect the wearer, J. Gen. Intern. Med., 35, 3063, 10.1007/s11606-020-06067-8
Geroski, 2000, Models of technology diffusion, Res. Policy, 29, 603, 10.1016/S0048-7333(99)00092-X
Gigerenzer, 1996, Reasoning the fast and frugal way: models of bounded rationality, Psychol. Rev., 103, 650, 10.1037/0033-295X.103.4.650
Gollwitzer, 2020, Partisan differences in physical distancing are linked to health outcomes during the COVID-19 pandemic, Nat. Hum. Behav., 4, 1186, 10.1038/s41562-020-00977-7
Granovetter, 1978, Threshold models of collective behavior, Am. J. Sociol., 83, 1420, 10.1086/226707
Hastings, 2013, Population dynamics, 175
Jackson, 1997, Social learning in recurring games, Games Econom. Behav., 21, 102, 10.1006/game.1997.0583
Juang, 2001, Learning from popularity, Econometrica, 69, 735, 10.1111/1468-0262.00211
Katz, 1982, Investigating the not invented here (NIH) syndrome: A look at the performance, tenure, and communication patterns of 50 R & D project groups, R&D Manag., 12, 7, 10.1111/j.1467-9310.1982.tb00478.x
Klayman, 1995, Varieties of confirmation bias, 385
Korn, 2020, Vaccination as a social contract, Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci., 117, 14890, 10.1073/pnas.1919666117
Lessig, 1995, The regulation of social meaning, Univ. Chic. Law Rev., 62, 943, 10.2307/1600054
Lohmann, 1994, The dynamics of informational cascades: The monday demonstrations in Leipzig, East Germany, 1989–91, World Politics, 47, 42, 10.2307/2950679
McAllister, 1991, Bandwagon, underdog, or projection? Opinion polls and electoral choice in Britain, 1979–1987, J. Politics, 53, 720, 10.2307/2131577
Miekisz, 2008, Evolutionary game theory and population dynamics, 269
Miller, 2013, The virus inoculum volume influences outcome of influenza A infection in mice, Lab. Anim., 47, 74, 10.1258/la.2012.011157
Morton, 2015, Exit polls, turnout, and bandwagon voting: Evidence from a natural experiment, Eur. Econ. Rev., 77, 65, 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2015.03.012
Nickerson, 1998, Confirmation bias: A ubiquitous phenomenon in many guises, Rev. Gen. Psychol., 2, 175, 10.1037/1089-2680.2.2.175
Orji, 2015, Gender, age, and responsiveness to Cialdini?s persuasion strategies, 147
Prather, 2020, Reducing transmission of SARS-CoV-2, Science, 368, 1422, 10.1126/science.abc6197
Prior, 2013, Media and political polarization, Annu. Rev. Political Sci., 16, 101, 10.1146/annurev-polisci-100711-135242
Rendell, 2011, Cognitive culture: theoretical and empirical insights into social learning strategies, Trends Cogn. Sci., 15, 68, 10.1016/j.tics.2010.12.002
Rothgerber, 2020
Sherif, 1966
Simon, 1990, A mechanism for social selection and successful altruism, Science, 250, 1665, 10.1126/science.2270480
Smith, 2000, Pathological outcomes of observational learning, Econometrica, 68, 371, 10.1111/1468-0262.00113
Surowiecki, 2005
Tajfel, 1979, An integrative theory of intergroup conflict, Soc. Psychol. Intergroup Relat., 33, 74
Tsoularis, 2002, Analysis of logistic growth models, Math. Biosci., 179, 21, 10.1016/S0025-5564(02)00096-2
Tucker, 2018, Social media, political polarization, and political disinformation: A review of the scientific literature
Tversky, 1974, Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases: Biases in judgments reveal some heuristics of thinking under uncertainty, Science, 185, 1124, 10.1126/science.185.4157.1124
Young, 2009, Innovation diffusion in heterogeneous populations: Contagion, social influence, and social learning, Amer. Econ. Rev., 99, 1899, 10.1257/aer.99.5.1899