Using Monte Carlo analysis to investigate the relationship between overconsumption and uncertain access to one's personal utility function
Tài liệu tham khảo
Agres, 1990
Alesina, 2005, Work and Leisure in the U.S. and Europe: Why so different?, vol. 2068
Ansolabehere, 1999, Replicating experiments using aggregate and survey data: the case of negative advertising and turnout, American Political Science Review, 93, 901, 10.2307/2586120
Argyle, 1999, Causes and correlates of happiness, 353
Ariely, 2000, Coherent arbitrariness: duration-sensitive pricing of hedonic stimuli around an arbitrary anchor
Ausubel, 1991, The failure of competition in the credit card market, American Economic Review, 81, 50
Becker, 1962, Irrational behavior and economic theory, Journal of Political Economy, 70, 1, 10.1086/258584
Binder, 1984, Preface, v, 10.1007/978-3-642-96788-7
Blanchard, 2004, The economic future of Europe, vol. 10310
Blanchflower, 2000, Well-Being Over Time in Britain and the USA, 7487
Booth, 2005, Hours of work and gender identity: does part-time work make the family happier?, vol. 507
Boumans, 2002, Modeling the dynamics of the integrated Earth System and the value of global economic services using the GUMBO Model, Ecological Economics, 41, 529, 10.1016/S0921-8009(02)00098-8
Brekke, 2003
Brickman, 1971, Hedonic relativism and planning the good society, 287
Brickman, 1978, Lottery winners and accident victims: is happiness relative?, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 37, 917, 10.1037/0022-3514.36.8.917
Danzinger, 2004
Davis, 2004, Tax effects on work activity, industry mix and shadow economy size: evidence from rich-country comparisons, vol. 10509
Diener, 2000, Money and happiness: income and subjective well-being across nations, 185
Diener, 1995, Factors predicting the subjective well-being of nations, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 69, 851, 10.1037/0022-3514.69.5.851
Easterlin, 1974, Does economic growth improve the human lot? Some empirical evidence, 89
Easterlin, 1995, Will raising the income of all increase the happiness of all?, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 27, 35, 10.1016/0167-2681(95)00003-B
Frey, 2002
Gilbert, 2002, The future is now: temporal correction in affective forecasting, Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 88, 430, 10.1006/obhd.2001.2982
Gold, 1993, On the need to mind the gap: on-line versus off-line cognitions underlying sexual risk-taking, 227
Hellström, 2001, Time-order effects for aesthetic preference, 421
Horton, 1984
Jones, 1998, Macroeconomic effects: the influence of advertising on overall sales levels, 326
Jorgenson, 1998
Kahneman, 2000, Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk, 17
Kalos, 1986
Knetsch, 1995, Asymmetric valuation of gains and losses and preference order assumptions, Economic Inquiry, 33, 134, 10.1111/j.1465-7295.1995.tb01851.x
Kumaraswamy, 1980, A generalized probability density function for double-bounded random processes, Journal of Hydrology, 46, 79, 10.1016/0022-1694(80)90036-0
Laibson, D., Repetto, A., Tobacman, J., 2004, Estimating discount functions from lifestyle consumption choices. Mimeo, Harvard.
Lane, 2000
Lazarus, 1984, On the primacy of cognition, American Psychologist, 39, 124, 10.1037/0003-066X.39.2.124
Little, 1957
Lowenstein, 1999, Wouldn't it be nice? Predicting future feelings, 85
Lowenstein, 1996, Hot/cold intrapersonal empathy gaps and the prediction of curiosity
Lowenstein, 1997, The effect of sexual arousal on predictions of sexual forcefulness, Journal of Crime and Delinquency, 34, 443, 10.1177/0022427897034004003
Lowenstein, 2003, Projection bias in predicting future utilities, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 1209, 10.1162/003355303322552784
Lynch, 1994, Toward a youth-centered prevention policy, 3
Madrian, 2006, The U.S. health care system and labor markets, vol. 11980
Mainwaring, 2001, Environmental values and the frame of reference, Ecology and Economics, 38, 391, 10.1016/S0921-8009(01)00175-6
March, 1958
McClure, 2004, Separate neural systems value immediate and delayed monetary rewards, Science, 306, 10.1126/science.1100907
Meadows, 1972
Meadows, 2003
Metropolis, 1947, Calculations in the liquid drop model of fission, Physical Review, 72, 186
Metropolis, 1953, Equation of state calculations by fast computing machines, Journal of Chemical Physics, 21, 1087, 10.1063/1.1699114
Mirlees, 1971, An exploration in the theory of optimal income taxation, Review of Economic Studies, 38, 175, 10.2307/2296779
Nash, 1984
Nelson, 1974, Advertising as information, Journal of Political Economy, 82, 729, 10.1086/260231
Nicholson, 1995
Nisbett, 1968, Obesity, hunger, and supermarket shopping behavior, Proceedings of the Annual Convention of the American Psychological Association, 3, 683
Ng, 1997, A case for happiness, cardinalism, and interpersonal comparability, The Economic Journal, 107, 1848, 10.1111/1468-0297.00262
Obstfeld, 2005, Global current account imbalances and exchange rate adjustments, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 67, 10.1353/eca.2005.0020
O'Donovan, 2000, Determinants of advertising expenditures: aggregate and cross-media evidence, International Journal of Advertising, 19, 317, 10.1080/02650487.2000.11104804
Page, 1968
Pang, 1997
Prescott, 2004, Why do Americans work so much more than Europeans?, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 28, 2
Press, 1992
Read, 2001, Is time-discounting hyperbolic or subadditive?, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 23, 5, 10.1023/A:1011198414683
Read, 1998, Predicting hunger: the effects of appetite and delay on choice, Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 76, 189, 10.1006/obhd.1998.2803
Robbins, 1932
Samuelson, 1938, A note on pure theory of consumer's behavior, Economica, 5, 61, 10.2307/2548836
Schkade, 1998, Does living in California make people happy? A focusing illusion in judgments of life satisfaction, Psychological Science, 9, 340, 10.1111/1467-9280.00066
Schmalensee, 1986, Advertising and market structure, 373
Schooler, 2003, The pursuit and assessment of happiness can be self-defeating, 41
Schwartz, 1983, Mood, misattribution and judgments of well-being: informative and directive function of affective states, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 45, 512
Scitovsky, 1976
Sen, 1967, Isolation, assurance, and the social rate of discount, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 81, 112, 10.2307/1879675
Sen, 1973, Behavior and the concept of preference, Economica, 40, 241, 10.2307/2552796
Simoes, 1999, Quantum chemistry qua applied mathematics. The contributions of Charles Alfred Coulson (1910–1974), Historical Studies in the Physical and Biological Sciences, 29, 363, 10.2307/27757814
Simon, 1974, Interpersonal welfare comparisons can be made and used for redistributive decision, Kyklos, 27, 63, 10.1111/j.1467-6435.1974.tb01898.x
Smith, 1776
Stigler, 1950, The development of utility theory, Journal of Political Economy, 58, 307, 10.1086/256962
Thaler, 1980, Toward a positive theory of consumer choice, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 1, 39, 10.1016/0167-2681(80)90051-7
Veerhoven, 1995, Satisfaction and social position: within nation differences, compared across nations, 254
Walther, 2004, Why sad people like shoes better: the influence of mood on the evaluative conditioning of consumer attitudes, Psychology and Marketing, 21, 755, 10.1002/mar.20028
Wänke, 1996, Comparative judgments as a function of the direction of comparison versus word order, Public Opinion Quarterly, 60, 400, 10.1086/297761
Weinstein, 1982, Community noise problems: evidence against adaptation, Journal of Environmental Psychology, 2, 87, 10.1016/S0272-4944(82)80041-8
Zeckhauser, 1973, Time as the ultimate source of utility, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87, 668, 10.2307/1882037
Zamagni, 2004, vol. III