Non-renewable resource extraction under financial incentives to reduce and reverse stock pollution

Journal of Environmental Economics and Management - Tập 92 - Trang 282-299 - 2018
Peifang Yang1, Graham A. Davis2
1Academy of Chinese Energy Strategy, China University of petroleum, Beijing, China
2Division of Economics and Business, Colorado School of Mines, USA

Tài liệu tham khảo

Aragón, 2016, Polluting industries and agricultural productivity: evidence from mining in Ghana, Econ. J., 126, 1980, 10.1111/ecoj.12244 Berger, 2011, The challenge of degraded environments: how common biases impair effective policy, Risk Anal., 31, 1423, 10.1111/j.1539-6924.2010.01477.x Burton, 2012, Public preferences for timeliness and quality of mine site rehabilitation. The case of bauxite mining in Western Australia, Resour. Pol., 37, 1, 10.1016/j.resourpol.2012.01.004 Cairns, 2004, Green accounting for an externality, pollution at a mine, Environ. Resour. Econ., 27, 409, 10.1023/B:EARE.0000018519.31028.97 Cairns, 2007, Strike when the force is with you: optimal stopping with application to resource equilibria, Am. J. Agric. Econ., 89, 461, 10.1111/j.1467-8276.2007.01016.x Cairns, 2015, Mineral depletion and the rules of resource dynamics, Energy J., 36, 159, 10.5547/01956574.36.SI1.rcai Davis, 2017, The odd notion of “reversible investment”, J. Bank. Finance, 81, 172, 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2016.03.019 Doole, 2013, Optimal dynamic regulation of the environmental impact of mining across diverse land types, N. Z. Econ. Pap., 47, 304 Falk, 1993, The economics of controlling stock pollutants: an efficient strategy for greenhouse gases, J. Environ. Econ. Manag., 25, 76, 10.1006/jeem.1993.1027 Farzin, 1996, Optimal pricing of environmental and natural resource use with stock externalities, J. Publ. Econ., 62, 31, 10.1016/0047-2727(96)01573-3 Farzin, 1996, Global carbon cycle and the optimal time path of a carbon tax, Oxf. Econ. Pap., 48, 515, 10.1093/oxfordjournals.oep.a028582 Forster, 1975, Optimal pollution control with a nonconstant exponential rate of decay, J. Environ. Econ. Manag., 2, 1, 10.1016/0095-0696(75)90016-9 Freeport-McMoRan. Mining reclamation in north america - supporting a sustainable future. https://www.fcx.com/sites/fcx/files/documents/fast%85/Mining_Recl_NA_2014.pd. Frosch, 2013, A15 Gorey, P. Compliance, Enforcement & Emerging Risks in Environmental Law – the DMIRS Perspective. https://www.nela.org.au/nela/documents/4GoreyPhilDr.pptx. (Accessed 25 September 2018). Government of Western Australia, 2012 Government of Western Australia, 2013 Government of Western Australia, 2014 Government of Western Australia, 2017 Hoel, 1996, Depletion of fossil fuels and the impacts of global warming, Resour. Energy Econ., 18, 115, 10.1016/0928-7655(96)00005-X Hong, 1995, Greenland ice evidence of hemispheric lead pollution two millennia ago by Greek and roman civilizations, Science, 265, 1841, 10.1126/science.265.5180.1841 Hotelling, 1931, The economics of exhaustible resources, J. Polit. Econ., 39, 137, 10.1086/254195 Keeler, 1971, The optimal control of pollution, J. Econ. Theor., 4, 19, 10.1016/0022-0531(72)90159-7 Keohane, 2007, Managing the quality of a resource with stock and flow controls, J. Publ. Econ., 91, 541, 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2006.06.003 Li, 2017, Exploring the impacts of coal mining on host communities in Shanxi, China – using subjective data, Resour. Pol., 53, 125, 10.1016/j.resourpol.2017.03.012 Lin, 1976, Land reclamation and strip-mined coal production in Appalachia, J. Environ. Econ. Manag., 3, 236, 10.1016/0095-0696(76)90023-1 2014 Muehlenbachs, 2015, A dynamic model of cleanup: estimating sunk costs in oil and gas production, Int. Econ. Rev., 56, 155, 10.1111/iere.12098 Nobbs, 1976, The economics of stock pollutants: the example of cadmium, Int. J. Environ. Stud., 8, 245, 10.1080/00207237608709741 Phillips, 1998, Restoring natural resources with destination-driven costs, J. Environ. Econ. Manag., 36, 225, 10.1006/jeem.1998.1051 Plourde, 1972, A model of waste accumulation and disposal, Can. J. Econ., 5, 119, 10.2307/133997 Randall, 1978, Reclaiming coal surface mines in central Appalachia: a case study of the benefits and costs, Land Econ., 54, 10.2307/3146172 Roan, 1996, Optimal production and reclamation at a mine site with an ecosystem constraint, J. Environ. Econ. Manag., 30, 186, 10.1006/jeem.1996.0013 2010 Schlottmann, 1976, Economic impacts of surface mine reclamation, Land Econ., 52, 265, 10.2307/3145526 Shi, 2013, Arsenic, copper, and zinc contamination in soil and wheat during coal mining, with assessment of health risks for the inhabitants of Huaibei, China, Environ. Sci. Pollut. Control Ser., 20, 8435, 10.1007/s11356-013-1842-3 2016 Ulph, 1994, The optimal time path of a carbon tax, Oxf. Econ. Pap., 46, 857, 10.1093/oep/46.Supplement_1.857 2016 United States Environmental Protection Agency (US EPA), 2004 United States Environmental Protection Agency (US EPA), 2015 United States Environmental Protection Agency (US EPA), 2016 United States Environmental Protection Agency (US EPA), 2016 United States Environmental Protection Agency (US EPA), 2016 United States Environmental Protection Agency (US EPA), 2016 United States Environmental Protection Agency (US EPA), 2017, Financial responsibility requirements under CERCLA section 108(b) for classes of facilities in the hardrock mining industry, Fed. Regist., 82, 3388 United States Environmental Protection Agency (US EPA), 2018, Financial responsibility requirements under cercla section 108(b) for classes of facilities in the hardrock mining industry, Fed. Regist., 83, 7556 White, 2015, Do control rights determine the optimal extension of liability to investors? The case of environmental policy for mines, J. Regul. Econ., 48, 26, 10.1007/s11149-015-9276-0 White, 2012, Optimal environmental policy design for mine rehabilitation and pollution with a risk of non-compliance owing to firm insolvency, Aust. J. Agric. Resour. Econ., 56, 280, 10.1111/j.1467-8489.2012.00591.x