Evolution, uncertainty, and the asymptotic efficiency of policy

Springer Science and Business Media LLC - Tập 192 - Trang 169-188 - 2022
Brian C. Albrecht1,2, Joshua R. Hendrickson3, Alexander William Salter4
1Coles College of Business, Kennesaw State University, Kennesaw, USA
2International Center for Law and Economics, Portland, USA
3University of Mississippi, University, USA
4Rawls College of Business, Texas Tech University, Lubbock, USA

Tóm tắt

Politics, like any social system, involves selection mechanisms. This paper presents a model of politics as an evolutionary process. Our model yields three main results. First, the political process selects for efficient policies in the long run. We call that attribute asymptotic efficiency. Second, bargaining amongst interest groups bounds the inefficiencies that can exist in the short run. Potential inefficiency declines when organizing interest groups becomes less costly. Finally, policies that appear to be inefficient in a static analysis can be efficient once economists consider the dynamic nature of political decisions. We argue that viewing the political process as a selection mechanism allows political economists to use efficiency as a criterion for positive economic analysis. In our approach, applied political economy involves looking for relevant costs that make the policy efficient. However, our approach does not rob political economists of the ability to make meaningful normative statements; it only constrains the type of statements made.

Tài liệu tham khảo

Acemoglu, D. (2003). Why not a political Coase theorem? Social conflict, commitment, and politics. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), 620–652. Aghion, P., Alesina, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Endogenous political institutions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(2), 565–611. Albrecht, B. C., & Kogelmann, B. (2020). Coasean causal inference: Using models as foils [working paper]. https://www.briancalbrecht.com/Albrecht_Kogelmann_Coasean_Inference.pdf Alchian, A. A. (1950). Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy, 58(3), 211–221. Ashworth, S. (2012). Electoral accountability: Recent theoretical and empirical work. Annual Review of Political Science, 15(1), 183–201. Barbera, S., & Jackson, M. O. (2004). Choosing how to choose: Self-stable majority rules and constitutions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(3), 1011–1048. Baron, D. P. (1994). Electoral competition with informed and uniformed voters. The American Political Science Review, 88(1), 33–47. Bassetto, M., & Sargent, T. J. (2006). Politics and efficiency of separating capital and ordinary government budgets. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4), 1167–1210. Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(3), 371–400. Boettke, P. J., Coyne, C. J., & Leeson, P. T. (2007). Saving government failure theory from itself: Recasting political economy from an Austrian perspective. Constitutional Political Economy, 18(2), 127–143. Brendon, C. (2013). Efficiency, equity, and optimal income taxation [working paper]. https://cadmus.eui.eu/handle/1814/27937 Breton, A. (1993). Toward a presumption of efficiency in politics. Public Choice, 77(1), 53–65. Buchanan, J. M. (1949). The pure theory of government finance: A suggested approach. Journal of Political Economy, 57(6), 496–505. Buchanan, J. M. (1959). Positive economics, welfare economics, and political economy. The Journal of Law and Economics, 2, 124–138. Buchanan, J. M. (1975). A contractarian paradigm for applying economic theory. The American Economic Review, 65(2), 225–230. Buchanan, J. M. (1987). The constitution of economic policy. Science, 236(4807), 1433–1436. Chamley, C. (1986). Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives. Econometrica, 54(3), 607–622. Chetty, R., Hendren, N., & Katz, L. F. (2016). The effects of exposure to better neighborhoods on children: New evidence from the moving to opportunity experiment. American Economic Review, 106(4), 855–902. Cheung, S. (1968). Private property rights and sharecropping. Journal of Political Economy, 76(6), 1107–1122. Cheung, S. (1970). The structure of a contract and the theory of a non-exclusive resource. The Journal of Law and Economics, 13(1), 49–70. Cheung, S. (1973). The fable of the bees: An economic investigation. The Journal of Law and Economics, 16(1), 11–33. Cheung, S. (1998). The transaction costs paradigm. Economic Inquiry, 36(4), 514–521. Clemens, M. A. (2011). Economics and emigration: Trillion-dollar bills on the sidewalk? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(3), 83–106. Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law & Economics, 3, 1–44. Diamond, P. A., & Mirrlees, J. A. (1971). Optimal taxation and public production I: Production efficiency. The American Economic Review, 61(1), 8–27. Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. Harper Collins. Duggan, J., & Martinelli, C. (2017). The political economy of dynamic elections: Accountability, commitment, and responsiveness. Journal of Economic Literature, 55(3), 916–984. Fiorina, M. P. (1981). Retrospective voting in American national elections. Yale University Press. Fox, J. (2007). Government transparency and policymaking. Public Choice, 131(1/2), 23–44. Gennaioli, N., & Shleifer, A. (2007). The evolution of common law. Journal of Political Economy, 115(1), 43–68. Golosov, M., Kocherlakota, N., & Tsyvinski, A. (2003). Optimal indirect and capital taxation. The Review of Economic Studies, 70(3), 569–587. Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1996). Electoral competition and special interest politics. The Review of Economic Studies, 63(2), 265–286. Heathcote, J., & Tsujiyama, H. (2021). Optimal income taxation: Mirrlees meets Ramsey. Journal of Political Economy, 129(11), 3141–3184. Hendrickson, J. R. (2019). U.S. maritime policy and economic efficiency (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. 3486330). Social Science Research Network. Hendrickson, J. R. (2020). Usury enforcement as an alternative to capital taxation in pre-modern states (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. 3652489). Social Science Research Network. Hendrickson, J. R., Salter, A. W., & Albrecht, B. C. (2018). Preventing plunder: Military technology, capital accumulation, and economic growth. Journal of Macroeconomics, 58, 154–173. IGM Forum. (n.d.). Steel and aluminum tariffs. https://www.igmchicago.org/surveys/steel-and-aluminum-tariffs/ Judd, K. L. (1985). Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model. Journal of Public Economics, 28(1), 59–83. Keen, M., & Wildasin, D. (2004). Pareto-efficient international taxation. American Economic Review, 94(1), 259–275. Leeson, P. T. (2012). Ordeals. The Journal of Law and Economics, 55(3), 691–714. Leeson, P. T. (2020). Logic is a harsh mistress: Welfare economics for economists. Journal of Institutional Economics, 16(2), 145–150. Lockwood, B. B., & Weinzierl, M. (2015). De gustibus non est taxandum: Heterogeneity in preferences and optimal redistribution. Journal of Public Economics, 124, 74–80. Lockwood, B. B., & Weinzierl, M. (2016). Positive and normative judgments implicit in U.S. tax policy, and the costs of unequal growth and recessions. Journal of Monetary Economics, 77, 30–47. Lohmann, S. (1998). An information rationale for the power of special interests. The American Political Science Review, 92(4), 809–827. Maskin, E., & Tirole, J. (2004). The politician and the judge: Accountability in government. American Economic Review, 94(4), 1034–1054. McCloskey, D. (1998). The so-called Coase theorem. Eastern Economic Journal, 24(3), 367–371. McCormick, R. E., Shughart, W. F., & Tollison, R. D. (1984). The disinterest in deregulation. The American Economic Review, 74(5), 1075–1079. Medema, S. G. (1994). The myth of two Coases: What Coase is really saying. Journal of Economic Issues, 28(1), 208–217. Munger, M. C. (2019). Tullock and the welfare costs of corruption: There is a “political Coase Theorem.” Public Choice, 181(1), 83–100. North, D. C. (1994). Economic performance through time. The American Economic Review, 84(3), 359–368. Olson, M. (1971). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Harvard University Press. Parisi, F. (2003). Political Coase theorem. Public Choice, 115(1), 1–36. Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. The Journal of Law & Economics, 19(2), 211–240. Posner, R. A. (1974). Theories of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5(2), 335–358. Priest, G. L. (1977). The common law process and the selection of efficient rules. The Journal of Legal Studies, 6(1), 65–82. Rubin, P. H. (1977). Why is the common law efficient? The Journal of Legal Studies, 6(1), 51–63. Stigler, G. J. (1966). The theory of price (3rd ed.). MacMillan Publishing. Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3. Stigler, G. (1992). Law or economics? Journal of Law and Economics, 35(2), 455–468. Stokey, N. L. (2008). The economics of inaction: Stochastic control models with fixed costs. Princeton University Press. Thompson, E. A. (2008). A rational alternative to social contract theory and correspondingly new theory of optimal government [working paper]. Available from authors upon request. Thompson, E. A. (1974). Taxation and national defense. Journal of Political Economy, 82(4), 755–782. Thompson, E. A. (1979). An economic basis for the “national defense argument” for aiding certain industries. Journal of Political Economy, 87(1), 1–36. Thompson, E. A., & Faith, R. L. (1981). A pure theory of strategic behavior and social institutions. The American Economic Review, 71(3), 366–380. Thompson, E. A., & Hickson, C. R. (2001). Ideology and the evolution of vital institutions. Springer. Tollison, R. D. (1988). Public choice and legislation. Virginia Law Review, 74(2), 339–371. Weingast, B. R., Shepsle, K. A., & Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy, 89(4), 642–664. Wittman, D. (1989). Why democracies produce efficient results. Journal of Political Economy, 97(6), 1395–1424.