A general concept of majority rule
Tài liệu tham khảo
Arrow, 1951
Barberá, 1979, Majority and positional voting in a probabilistic framework, The Review of Economic Studies, 46, 379, 10.2307/2297058
Barberá, 1986, Falmagne and the rationalizability of stochastic choices in terms of random orderings, Econometrica, 54, 707, 10.2307/1911317
Ben-Akiva, 1985
Block, 1960, Random orderings and stochastic theories of responses, 97
Bogart, 1976, A bound on the dimension of interval orders, Journal of Combinatorial Theory, 21, 319, 10.1016/0097-3165(76)90004-2
Brady, 1989, The nature of utility functions in mass publics, American Political Science Review, 83, 143, 10.2307/1956438
Coughlin, 1992
Critchlow, 1991, Probability models on rankings, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 35, 294, 10.1016/0022-2496(91)90050-4
1993
DeMeyer, 1970, The probability of a cyclical majority, Econometrica, 38, 345, 10.2307/1913015
Duggan, 1999, A general extension theorem for binary relations, Journal of Economic Theory, 86, 1, 10.1006/jeth.1998.2504
Enelow, 1984, Probabilistic voting and the importance of centrist ideologies in democratic elections, Journal of Politics, 46, 459, 10.2307/2130970
Enelow, 1989, A general probabilistic model of spatial voting, Public Choice, 61, 101, 10.1007/BF00115657
Falmagne, 1978, A representation theorem for finite random scale systems, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 18, 52, 10.1016/0022-2496(78)90048-2
Falmagne, 1997, Stochastic token theory, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 41, 129, 10.1006/jmps.1996.1141
Falmagne, 1996, Random utility models for approval voting, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 40, 152, 10.1006/jmps.1996.0014
Feld, 1986, Partial single-peakedness: an extension and clarification, Public Choice, 51, 71, 10.1007/BF00141686
Fishburn, 1970, Intransitive indifference in preference theory, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 7, 207
Fishburn, 1975, A probabilistic model of social choice: comment, Review of Economic Studies, 42, 297, 10.2307/2296538
Fishburn, 1984, Probabilistic social choice based on simple voting comparisons, Review of Economic Studies, 51, 683, 10.2307/2297786
Fishburn, 1985
Fishburn, 1992, Induced binary probabilities and the linear ordering polytope: a status report, Mathematical Social Sciences, 23, 67, 10.1016/0165-4896(92)90038-7
Fishburn, 1998, Stochastic utility, 273
Fishburn, 1977, Towards a theory of elections with probabilistic preferences, Econometrica, 45, 1907, 10.2307/1914118
Gaertner, 1978, Cyclically mixed preferences—a necessary and sufficient condition for transitivity of the social preference relation, 169
Gehrlein, 1989, The probability of intransitivity of pairwise comparisons in individual preference, Mathematical Social Sciences, 17, 67, 10.1016/0165-4896(89)90017-6
Gehrlein, 1976, The probability of the paradox of voting: a computable solution, Journal of Economic Theory, 13, 14, 10.1016/0022-0531(76)90063-6
Grandmont, 1978, Intermediate preferences and the majority rule, Econometrica, 46, 317, 10.2307/1913903
Heyer, 1989, Elements of a model-theoretic framework for probabilistic measurement, 99
Heyer, 1992, Generalizing the concept of binary choice systems induced by rankings: one way of probabilizing deterministic measurement structures, Mathematical Social Sciences, 23, 31, 10.1016/0165-4896(92)90036-5
Intriligator, 1973, A probabilistic model of social choice, Review of Economic Studies, 40, 552, 10.2307/2296588
Joe, 1997
Jones, 1995, Condorcet winners and the paradox of voting: probability calculations for weak preference orders, The American Political Science Review, 89, 137, 10.2307/2083080
Kahneman, 1979, Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk, Econometrica, 47, 263, 10.2307/1914185
Koppen, 1995, Random utility representation of binary choice probabilities: critical graphs yielding critical necessary conditions, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 39, 21, 10.1006/jmps.1995.1003
Krantz, 1971, Vol. 1
Loomes, 1982, Regret theory—an alternative theory of rational choice under uncertainty, Economic Journal, 92, 805, 10.2307/2232669
Luce, 1956, Semiorders and a theory of utility discrimination, Econometrica, 26, 178, 10.2307/1905751
Luce, 1959
Luce, 1965, Preference, utility and subjective probability, Vol. III, 249
Luce, 1994, What common ground exists for descriptive, prescriptive, and normative utility theories?, Management Science, 40, 263, 10.1287/mnsc.40.2.263
Mallows, 1957, Non-null ranking models I, Biometrika, 44, 114, 10.1093/biomet/44.1-2.114
Marley, 1991, Context dependent probabilistic choice models based on measures of binary advantage, Mathematical Social Sciences, 21, 201, 10.1016/0165-4896(91)90028-P
Marschak, 1960, Binary-choice constraints and random utility indicators, 312
McFadden, 1991, Advances in computation, statistical methods, and testing of discrete choice models, Marketing Letters, 2, 215, 10.1007/BF02404073
McFadden, D., 1998. Specification of econometric models. Econometrica, in press.
Niederée, 1997, Generalized random utility models and the representational theory of measurement: a conceptual link, 155
Rabinovitch, 1978, The dimension of semiorders, Journal of Combinatorial Theory, 25, 50, 10.1016/0097-3165(78)90030-4
Regenwetter, 1996, Random utility representations of finite m-ary relations, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 40, 219, 10.1006/jmps.1996.0022
Regenwetter, 1997, Probabilistic preferences and topset voting, Mathematical Social Sciences, 34, 91, 10.1016/S0165-4896(97)00012-7
Regenwetter, M., Adams, J., Grofman, B., 2002a. On the Sample Condorcet efficiency of majority rule: an alternative view of majority cycles and social homogeneity. Theory and Decision, conditionally accepted pending minor revision.
Regenwetter, 1999, A stochastic model of preference change and its application to 1992 presidential election panel data, Psychological Review, 106, 362, 10.1037/0033-295X.106.2.362
Regenwetter, 1998, Approval voting, Borda winners and Condorcet winners: evidence from seven elections, Management Science, 44, 520, 10.1287/mnsc.44.4.520
Regenwetter, 1998, Choosing subsets: a size-independent probabilistic model and the quest for a social welfare ordering, Social Choice and Welfare, 15, 423, 10.1007/s003550050115
Regenwetter, 2002, On the model dependence of majority preferences reconstructed from ballot or survey data, Mathematical Social Sciences, 43/3, 453
Regenwetter, 2001, Random relations, random utilities, and random functions, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 45, 864, 10.1006/jmps.2000.1357
Roberts, 1979
Saari, 1995
Schofield, 1992, Probability and convergence for supra-majority rule with euclidean preferences, Mathematical Computer Modelling, 16, 41, 10.1016/0895-7177(92)90086-Z
Suck, 1992, Geometric and combinatorial properties of the polytope of binary choice probabilities, Mathematical Social Sciences, 23, 81, 10.1016/0165-4896(92)90039-8
Suck, R., 1995. Random utility representations based on semiorders, interval orders, and partial orders. Manuscript at Universität Osnabrück.
Tangian, 2000, Unlikelihood of Condorcet’s paradox in a large society, Social Choice and Welfare, 17, 337, 10.1007/s003550050024
Thurstone, 1927, A law of comparative judgement, Psychological Review, 34, 273, 10.1037/h0070288
Thurstone, 1927, Three psychophysical laws, Psychophysical Review, 34, 424, 10.1037/h0073028
Trotter, 1992
Tsetlin, I., Regenwetter, M., 2002. On the probability of correct or incorrect majority preference relations. Social Choice and Welfare, in press.
Tsetlin, I., Regenwetter, M., Grofman, B., 2002. The impartial culture maximizes the probability of majority cycles. Social Choice and Welfare, in press.
Tversky, 1969, Intransitivity of preferences, Psychological Review, 76, 31, 10.1037/h0026750
Tversky, 1986, Rational choice and the framing of decisions, Journal of Business, 59, 251, 10.1086/296365
Van Deemen, 1999, The probability of the paradox of voting for weak preference orderings, Social Choice and Welfare, 16, 171, 10.1007/s003550050138
Vila, 1998, On the intransitivity of preferences consistent with similarity relations, Journal of Economic Theory, 79, 281, 10.1006/jeth.1997.2378