Preferences for power
Tài liệu tham khảo
Abbink, 2009, The pleasure of being nasty, Econ. Lett., 105, 306, 10.1016/j.econlet.2009.08.024
Aghion, 1992, An incomplete contracts approach to financial contracting, Rev. Econ. Stud., 59, 473, 10.2307/2297860
Agranov, 2017, Stochastic choice and preferences for randomization, J. Polit. Econ., 125, 40, 10.1086/689774
Andreoni, 1990, Impure altruism and donations to public goods: a theory of warm-glow giving, Econ. J., 100, 464, 10.2307/2234133
Andreoni, 1995, Warm-glow versus cold-prickle: the effects of positive and negative framing on cooperation in experiments, Q. J. Econ., 110, 1, 10.2307/2118508
Barclay, 1989, Private benefits from control of public corporations, J. Financ. Econ., 25, 371, 10.1016/0304-405X(89)90088-3
Bardsley, 2008, Dictator game giving: altruism or artefact?, Exp. Econ., 11, 122, 10.1007/s10683-007-9172-2
Bartling, 2011, Shifting the blame: on delegation and responsibility, Rev. Econ. Stud., 79, 67, 10.1093/restud/rdr023
Bartling, 2014, 2005
Battigalli, 2007, Guilt in games, Am. Econ. Rev., 97, 170, 10.1257/aer.97.2.170
Battigalli, 2009, Dynamic psychological games, J. Econ. Theory, 144, 1, 10.1016/j.jet.2008.01.004
Bendahan, 2015, Leader corruption depends on power and testosterone, Leadersh. Q., 26, 101, 10.1016/j.leaqua.2014.07.010
Blount, 1995, When social outcomes aren’t fair: the effect of causal attributions on preferences, Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process., 63, 131, 10.1006/obhd.1995.1068
Bown, 2003, The lure of choice, J. Behav. Decis. Mak., 16, 297, 10.1002/bdm.447
Brandts, 2011, The strategy versus the direct-response method: a first survey of experimental comparisons, Exp. Econ., 14, 375, 10.1007/s10683-011-9272-x
Brosig-Koch, 2017, The dynamics of behavior in modified dictator games, PLoS One, 12, 10.1371/journal.pone.0176199
Cappelen, 2013, Give and take in dictator games, Econ. Lett., 118, 280, 10.1016/j.econlet.2012.10.030
Charness, 2004, Attribution and reciprocity in an experimental labor market, J. Labor Econ., 22, 665, 10.1086/383111
Charness, 2007, Intention and stochastic outcomes: an experimental study, Econ. J., 117, 1051, 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02066.x
Charness, 2006, Promises and partnership, Econometrica, 74, 1579, 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00719.x
Charness, 2002, Understanding social preferences with simple tests, Q. J. Econ., 117, 817, 10.1162/003355302760193904
Charness, 2014, The dark side of competition for status, Manag. Sci., 60, 38, 10.1287/mnsc.2013.1747
Chassang, 2019
Chen, 2009, Group identity and social preferences, Am. Econ. Rev., 99, 431, 10.1257/aer.99.1.431
Coffman, 2011, Intermediation reduces punishment (and reward), American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 3, 77
Cox, 2007, A tractable model of reciprocity and fairness, Games and Economic Behavior, 59, 17, 10.1016/j.geb.2006.05.001
Cox, 2008, Revealed altruism, Econometrica, 76, 31, 10.1111/j.0012-9682.2008.00817.x
Crumpler, 2008, An experimental test of warm glow giving, J. Public Econ., 92, 1011, 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.12.014
Dahya, 2008, Dominant shareholders, corporate boards, and corporate value: a cross-country analysis, J. Financ. Econ., 87, 73, 10.1016/j.jfineco.2006.10.005
Demsetz, 1985, The structure of corporate ownership: causes and consequences, J. Polit. Econ., 93, 1155, 10.1086/261354
Dessein, Wouter, and Richard Holden. 2019. “Organizations with power-hungry agents.” CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP13526.
Doidge, 2009, Private benefits of control, ownership, and the cross-listing decision, J. Financ., 64, 425, 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2008.01438.x
Dufwenberg, 2000, Reciprocity and wage undercutting, Eur. Econ. Rev., 44, 1069, 10.1016/S0014-2921(99)00047-1
Dufwenberg, 2004, A theory of sequential reciprocity, Games and Economic Behavior, 47, 268, 10.1016/j.geb.2003.06.003
Dyck, 2004, Private benefits of control: an international comparison, J. Financ., 59, 537, 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2004.00642.x
Ederer, 2017, Promises and expectations, Games and Economic Behavior, 106, 161, 10.1016/j.geb.2017.09.012
Ellingsen, 2010, Testing guilt aversion, Games and Economic Behavior, 68, 95, 10.1016/j.geb.2009.04.021
Emerson, 1962, Power-dependence relations, The American Sociological Review, 31, 10.2307/2089716
Falk, 2006, A theory of reciprocity, Games and Economic Behavior, 54, 293, 10.1016/j.geb.2005.03.001
Falk, 2003, On the nature of fair behavior, Econ. Inq., 41, 20, 10.1093/ei/41.1.20
Falk, 2008, Testing theories of fairness – intentions matter, Games and Economic Behavior, 62, 287, 10.1016/j.geb.2007.06.001
Fehr, 2013, The lure of authority: motivation and incentive effects of power, Am. Econ. Rev., 103, 1325, 10.1257/aer.103.4.1325
Ferreira, 2017, On the roots of the intrinsic value of decision rights: evidence from France and Japan
Fershtman, 2001, Strategic delegation: an experiment, RAND J. Econ., 352, 10.2307/2696414
Fischbacher, 2007, z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments, Exp. Econ., 10, 171, 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4
Fiske, 1993, Controlling other people: the impact of power on stereotyping, Am. Psychol., 48, 621, 10.1037/0003-066X.48.6.621
Fiske, 1996, Control, interdependence and power: understanding social cognition in its social context, Eur. Rev. Soc. Psychol., 7, 31, 10.1080/14792779443000094
Geanakoplos, 1989, Psychological games and sequential rationality, Games and Economic Behavior, 1, 60, 10.1016/0899-8256(89)90005-5
Grossman, 1986, The costs and benefits of ownership: a theory of vertical and lateral integration, J. Polit. Econ., 94, 691, 10.1086/261404
Gul, 2016, Interdependent preference models as a theory of intentions, J. Econ. Theory, 165, 179, 10.1016/j.jet.2016.04.009
Hart, 1995, Debt and seniority: an analysis of the role of hard claims in constraining management, Am. Econ. Rev., 85, 567
Hart, 2005, On the design of hierarchies: coordination versus specialization, J. Polit. Econ., 113, 675, 10.1086/431794
Jensen, 1976, Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure, J. Financ. Econ., 3, 305, 10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-X
Keltner, 2003, Power, approach, and inhibition, Psychol. Rev., 110, 265, 10.1037/0033-295X.110.2.265
Korenok, 2014, Taking, giving, and impure altruism in dictator games, Exp. Econ., 17, 488, 10.1007/s10683-013-9379-3
Krupka, 2013, Identifying social norms using coordination games: why does dictator game sharing vary?, J. Eur. Econ. Assoc., 11, 495, 10.1111/jeea.12006
Lazear, 2012, Sorting in experiments with application to social preferences, Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ., 4, 136, 10.1257/app.4.1.136
Levine, 1998, Modeling altruism and spitefulness in experiments, Rev. Econ. Dyn., 1, 593, 10.1006/redy.1998.0023
List, 2007, On the interpretation of giving in dictator games, J. Polit. Econ., 115, 482, 10.1086/519249
List, 2016, Multiple hypothesis testing in experimental economics, Exp. Econ., 1
Magee, 2008, 8 social hierarchy: the self-reinforcing nature of power and status, Acad. Manag. Ann., 2, 351, 10.5465/19416520802211628
McCabe, 1998, Reciprocity, trust, and payoff privacy in extensive form bargaining, Games and Economic Behavior, 24, 10, 10.1006/game.1998.0638
Neri, 2017
Orhun, 2018, Perceived motives and reciprocity, Games and Economic Behavior, 109, 436, 10.1016/j.geb.2018.01.002
Owens, 2014, The control premium: a preference for payoff autonomy, American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 6, 138
de Quidt, 2018, Experimenter demand effects, Handbook of Research Methods and Applications in Experimental Economics, forthcoming., 384
De Quidt, 2018, Measuring and bounding experimenter demand, Am. Econ. Rev., 108, 3266, 10.1257/aer.20171330
Rabin, 1993, Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics, Am. Econ. Rev., 1281
Rand, 2015, It’s the thought that counts: the role of intentions in noisy repeated games, J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 116, 481, 10.1016/j.jebo.2015.05.013
Sebald, 2010, Attribution and reciprocity, Games and Economic Behavior, 68, 339, 10.1016/j.geb.2009.07.004
Segal, 2007, Tit for tat: foundations of preferences for reciprocity in strategic settings, J. Econ. Theory, 136, 197, 10.1016/j.jet.2006.07.003
Selten, 1967, Die Strategiemethode zur Erforschung des engeschraänkt rationalen Verhaltens im Rahmen eines Oligopolexperiments, 136
Sloof, 2017, Illusion of control and the pursuit of authority, Exp. Econ., 20, 556, 10.1007/s10683-016-9499-7
Sobel, 2005, Interdependent preferences and reciprocity, J. Econ. Lit., 43, 392, 10.1257/0022051054661530
Tost, 2015, When, why, and how do powerholders “feel the power”? Examining the links between structural and psychological power and reviving the connection between power and responsibility, Res. Organ. Behav., 35, 29
Toussaert, 2017, Intention-based reciprocity and signaling of intentions, J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 137, 132, 10.1016/j.jebo.2017.03.001
Vanberg, 2008, Why do people keep their promises? An experimental test of two explanations, Econometrica, 76, 1467, 10.3982/ECTA7673
Zizzo, 2001, Are people willing to pay to reduce others’ incomes?, Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, 39, 10.2307/20076295
Bolton, 2000, ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition, Am. Econ. Rev., 166, 10.1257/aer.90.1.166
Fehr, 1999, A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation, Q. J. Econ., 114, 817, 10.1162/003355399556151