On the Supposed Evidence for Libertarian Paternalism
Tóm tắt
Can the general public learn to deal with risk and uncertainty, or do authorities need to steer people’s choices in the right direction? Libertarian paternalists argue that results from psychological research show that our reasoning is systematically flawed and that we are hardly educable because our cognitive biases resemble stable visual illusions. For that reason, they maintain, authorities who know what is best for us need to step in and steer our behavior with the help of “nudges.” Nudges are nothing new, but justifying them on the basis of a latent irrationality is. In this article, I analyze the scientific evidence presented for such a justification. It suffers from narrow logical norms, that is, a misunderstanding of the nature of rational thinking, and from a confirmation bias, that is, selective reporting of research. These two flaws focus the blame on individuals’ minds rather than on external causes, such as industries that spend billions to nudge people into unhealthy behavior. I conclude that the claim that we are hardly educable lacks evidence and forecloses the true alternative to nudging: teaching people to become risk savvy.
Tài liệu tham khảo
Aki, E.A., A.D. Oxman, J. Herrin, G.E. Vist, I. Terrenato, F. Sperati, et al. 2011. Using alternative statistical formats for presenting risks and risk reductions. Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews 3, CD006776.
Anderson, J.R. 1990. The adaptive character of thought. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
Arie, S. 2013. Uruguay’s mandatory breast cancer screening for working women aged 40–59 is challenged. British Medical Journal 346: f1907.
Ariely, D. 2008. Predictably irrational: the hidden forces that shape our decisions, 1st ed. New York: HarperCollins.
Arkes, H. R., Gigerenzer, G., and Hertwig, R. 2015. Coherence cannot be a universal criterion for rational behavior: a systematic and theoretical review. Submitted manuscript.
Baratgin, J., and I.A. Noveck. 2000. Not only base rates are neglected in the engineer-lawyer problem: an investigation of reasoners’ underutilization of complementarity. Memory & Cognition 28: 79–91.
Bazerman, M.H., and M.A. Neale. 1986. Heuristics in negotiation: limitations to effective dispute resolution. In Judgment and decision making: an interdisciplinary reader, ed. H.R. Arkes and R.R. Hammond, 311–321. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.
Berg, N., and G. Gigerenzer. 2007. Psychology implies paternalism? Bounded rationality may reduce the rationale to regulate risk-taking. Social Choice and Welfare 28: 337–359.
Berg, N., and G. Gigerenzer. 2010. As-if behavioral economics: neoclassical economics in disguise? History of Economic Ideas 18: 133–165.
Berrington de González, A., M. Mahesh, K.P. Kim, M. Bhargavan, R. Lewis, F. Mettler, et al. 2009. Projected cancer risk from computed tomography scans performed in the United States in 2007. Archives of Internal Medicine 189: 2071–2077.
Binmore, K. 2008. Rational decisions in large worlds. Annales d’Ecomonie et de Statistique 86: 25–41.
Bond, M. 2009. Risk school. Nature 461(29): 1189–1192.
Brase, G. 2007. The (in)flexibility of evolved frequency representations for statistical reasoning: cognitive styles and brief prompts do not influence Bayesian inference. Acta Psychologica Sinica 39: 398–405.
Brase, G. 2009. Pictorial representations and numerical representations in Bayesian reasoning. Applied Cognitive Psychology 23(3): 369–381. doi:10.1002/acp.1460.
Brenner, D.J., and E.J. Hall. 2007. Computed tomography—an increasing source of radiation exposure. New England Journal of Medicine 357: 2277–2284. doi:10.1056/NEJMra072149.
Brodie, J., I. Daubechies, C. De Mol, D. Giannone, and I. Loris. 2009. Sparse and stable Markowitz portfolios. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 106(30): 12267–12272. doi:10.1073/pnas.0904287106.
Chater, N., and M. Oaksford (eds.). 2008. The probabilistic mind: prospects for Bayesian cognitive science. Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.
Chater, N., J.B. Tenenbaum, and A. Yuille. 2006. Probabilistic models of cognition: conceptual foundations. Trends in Cognitive Sciences 10: 335–344.
Cohen, D., and P. Carter. 2010. WHO and the pandemic flu “conspiracies”. British Medical Journal 340: 1274–1279. doi:10.1136/bmj.c2912.
Cosmides, L., and J. Tooby. 1996. Are humans good intuitive statisticians after all? Rethinking some conclusions from the literature on judgment under uncertainty. Cognition 58: 1–73. doi:10.1016/0010-0277(95)00664-8.
Dawes, R.M., and M. Mulford. 1996. The false consensus effect and overconfidence: flaws in judgment, or flaws in how we study judgment? Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 65: 201–211. doi:10.1006/obhd.1996.0020.
DeMiguel, V., L. Garlappi, and R. Uppal. 2009. Optimal versus naive diversification: how inefficient Is the 1/N portfolio strategy? Review of Financial Studies 22: 1915–1953. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhm075.
Edwards, W. 1968. Conservatism in human information processing. In Formal representation of human judgment, ed. B. Kleinmuntz, 17–52. New York: Wiley.
Erev, I., T.S. Wallsten, and D.V. Budescu. 1994. Simultaneous over- and underconfidence: the role of error in judgment processes. Psychological Review 101: 519–527. doi:10.1037/0033-295X.101.3.519.
Feynman, R.P. 1967. The character of physical law. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Fiedler, K. 1988. The dependence of the conjunction fallacy on subtle linguistic factors. Psychological Research 50: 123–129. doi:10.1007/BF00309212.
Fong, G.T., D.H. Krantz, and R.E. Nisbett. 1986. The effects of statistical training on thinking about everyday problems. Cognitive Psychology 18: 253–292.
Friston, K. 2010. The free-energy principle: a unified brain theory? Nature Reviews Neuroscience 11(2): 127–138. doi:10.1038/nrn2787.
Gigerenzer, G. 2000. Adaptive thinking: rationality in the real world. New York: Oxford University Press.
Gigerenzer, G. 2014a. Breast cancer screening pamphlets mislead women: all women and women’s organnisations should trear up the pink ribbons and campaign for honest information. British Medical Journal 348: g2636.
Gigerenzer, G. 2014b. Risk savvy: how to make good decisions. New York: Viking.
Gigerenzer, G., and H. Brighton. 2009. Homo heuristicus: why biased minds make better inferences. Topics in Cognitive Science 1: 107–143. doi:10.1111/j.1756-8765.2008.01006.x.
Gigerenzer, G., Todd, P. M., and the ABC Research Group. 1999. Simple heuristics that make us smart. New York: Oxford University Press.
Gigerenzer, G., and U. Hoffrage. 1995. How to improve Bayesian reasoning without instruction: frequency formats. Psychological Review 102: 684–704.
Gigerenzer, G., and J.A. Muir Gray (eds.). 2011. Better doctors, better patients, better decisions: envisioning health care 2020. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Gigerenzer, G., and R. Selten (eds.). 2001. Bounded rationality: the adaptive toolbox. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Gigerenzer, G., W. Hell, and H. Blank. 1988. Presentation and content: the use of base rates as a continuous variable. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 14: 513–525. doi:10.1037/0096-1523.14.3.513.
Gigerenzer, G., W. Gaissmaier, E. Kurz-Milcke, L.M. Schwartz, and S. Woloshin. 2007. Helping doctors and patients to make sense of health statistics. Psychological Science in the Public Interest 8: 53–96.
Gigerenzer, G., J. Mata, and R. Frank. 2009. Public knowledge of benefits of breast and prostate cancer screening in Europe. Journal of the National Cancer Institute 101: 1216–1220.
Gigerenzer, G., R. Hertwig, and T. Pachur (eds.). 2011. Heuristics: the foundations of adaptive behavior. New York: Oxford University Press.
Gigerenzer, G., K. Fiedler, and H. Olsson. 2012. Rethinking cognitive biases as environmental consequences. In Ecological rationality: intelligence in the world, ed. P.M. Todd, G. Gigerenzer, and the ABC Research Group, 80–110. New York: Oxford University Press.
Gøtzsche, P.C., and K.J. Jørgensen. 2013. Screening for breast cancer with mammography. Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews 6, CD001877. doi:10.1002/14651858.
Griffiths, T.L., C. Kemp, and J.B. Tenenbaum. 2008. Bayesian models of cognition. In Cambridge handbook of computational cognitive modeling, ed. R. Sun, 59–100. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Hertwig, R., and I. Erev. 2009. The description-experience gap in risky choice. Trends in Cognitive Sciences 13: 517–523. doi:10.1016/j.tics.2009.09.004.
Hertwig, R., and G. Gigerenzer. 1999. The “conjunction fallacy” revisited: how intelligent inferences look like reasoning errors. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 12: 275–305. doi:10.1002/(SICI)1099-0771(199912)12:4<275::AID-BDM323>3.0.CO;2-M.
Hertwig, R., T. Pachur, and S. Kurzenhäuser. 2005. The accuracy and processes of judgments of risk frequencies. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory & Cognition 31: 621–642. doi:10.1037/0278-7393.31.4.621.
Hoffrage, U., S. Lindsey, R. Hertwig, and G. Gigerenzer. 2000. Communicating statistical information. Science 290: 2261–2262. doi:10.1126/science.290.5500.2261.
House of Lords. Science and Technology Select Committee. 2011. 2nd Report of Session 2010–12: Behaviour Change. London: Authority of the House of Lords.
Inhelder, B., and Piaget, J. 1964. The early growth of logic in the child (E. A. Lunzer, trans.). New York: Norton Library (Original work published 1959)
Johnson, E.J., and D.G. Goldstein. 2003. Do defaults save lives? Science 302: 1338–1339. doi:10.1126/science.1091721.
Juslin, P., A. Winman, and H. Olsson. 2000. Naive empiricism and dogmatism in confidence research: a critical examination of the hard-easy effect. Psychological Review 107: 384–396. doi:10.1037/0033-295X.107.2.384.
Juslin, P., A. Winman, and P. Hansson. 2007. The naïve intuitive statistician: a naïve sampling model of intuitive confidence intervals. Psychological Review 114: 678–703. doi:10.1037/0033-295X.114.3.678.
Kahan, D. 2000. Gentle nudges versus hard shoves: solving the sticky norms problem. Unversity of Chicago Law Review 67: 607–646.
Kahneman, D. 2011. Thinking fast and slow. London: Allen Lane.
Kahneman, D., and A. Tversky. 1972. Subjective probability: a judgment of representativeness. Cognitive Psychology, 3, 430–454. In Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases, ed. D. Kahneman, P. Slovic, and A. Tversky, 1932–1947. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.
Kahneman, D., and A. Tversky. 1973. On the psychology of prediction. Psychological Review 80: 237–251. doi:10.1037/h0034747.
Kleiter, G.D. 1994. Natural sampling: rationality without base rates. In Contributions to mathematical psychology, psyxhometrics, and methodology, ed. G.H. Fischer and D. Laming, 375–388. New York: Springer.
Knight, F. 1921. Risk, uncertainty and profit, XXXIth ed. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Kösters, J.P., and P.C. Gøtzsche. 2003. Regular self-examination or clinical examination for early detection of breast cancer. Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews 2, CD003373.
Kruglanski, A.W., and G. Gigerenzer. 2011. Intuitive and deliberative judgments are based on common principles. Psychological Review 118: 97–109. doi:10.1037/a0020762.
Kühberger, A. 1995. The framing of decisions: a new look at old problems. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 62: 230–240. doi:10.1006/obhd.1995.1046.
Kühberger, A., and P. Gradl. 2013. Choice, rating, and ranking: framing effects with different response modes. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 26(2): 109–117. doi:10.1002/bdm.764.
Kühberger, A., and C. Tanner. 2010. Risky choice framing: task versions and a comparison of prospect theory and fuzzy-trace theory. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 23(3): 314–329.
Lindsey, S., R. Hertwig, and G. Gigerenzer. 2003. Communicating statistical DNA evidence. Jurimetrics 43: 147–163.
Mandel, D.R. 2001. Gain-loss framing and choice: separating outcome formulations from descriptor formulations. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 85(1): 56–76. doi:10.1006/obhd.2000.2932.
McKenzie, C.R.M., and J.D. Nelson. 2003. What a speaker’s choice of frame reveals: reference points, frame selection, and framing effects. Psychonomic Bulletin and Review 10: 596–602. doi:10.3758/BF03196520.
McKenzie, C.R.M., M.J. Liersch, and S.R. Finkelstein. 2006. Recommendations implicit in policy defaults. Psychological Science 17: 414–420. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9280.2006.01721.x.
Meyerowtiz, B.E., and S. Chaiken. 1987. The effect of message framing on breast self-examination attitudes, intentions, and behavior. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 52(3): 509–510.
Moxey, A., D. O’Connell, P. McGettigan, and D. Henry. 2003. Describing treatment effects to patients: how they are expressed makes a difference. Journal of General Internal Medicine 18: 948–959. doi:10.1046/j.1525-1497.2003.20928.x.
Multmeier, J. 2012. Representations facilitate Bayesian reasoning: computational facilitation and ecological design revisited. Unpublished manuscript.
Nisbett, R.E. 2009. Intelligence and how to get it: why schools and cultures count. New York: Norton.
Norman, D. 1990. The design of everyday things. New York: Doubleday.
Olsson, H. 2014. Measuring overconfidence: methodological problems and statistical artifacts. Journal of Business Research 67: 1766–1770. doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2014.03.002.
Parikh, P. 2009. Value investing and behavioral finance: insight into the Indian stock market. New Delhi: Tata McGraw-Hill Education.
Rebonato, R. 2012. Taking liberties: a critical examination of libertarian paternalism. Basingstoke, United Kingdom: Palgrave Macmillan.
Salovey, P., and P. Williams-Piehota. 2004. Field experiments in social psychology: message framing and the promotion of health protective behaviors. American Behavioral Scientist 47: 488–505. doi:10.1177/0002764203259293.
Savage, L.J. 1954. The foundations of statistics. New York: Wiley.
Schooler, L.J., and J.R. Anderson. 1997. The role of process in the rational analysis of memory. Cognitive Psychology 32: 219–250. doi:10.1006/cogp.1997.0652.
Sedlmeier, P., and G. Gigerenzer. 2001. Teaching Bayesian reasoning in less than two hours. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General 130: 380–400. doi:10.1037/0096-3445.130.3.380.
Sen, A. 1993. Internal consistency of choice. Econometrica 61: 495–521.
Shapira, M.M., A.B... Nattinger, and C.A. McHorney. 2011. Frequency or probability? a qualitative study of risk communication formats used in health care. Medical Decision Making 21(6): 459–467.
Sher, S., and C.R.M. McKenzie. 2006. Information leakage from logically equivalent frames. Cognition 101: 467–494.
Simon, H.A. 1985. Human nature in politics: the dialogue of psychology with political science. American Political Science Review 79: 293–304.
Slovic, P., B. Fischhoff, and S. Lichtenstein. 1982. Facts versus fears: understanding perceived risk. In Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases, ed. D. Kahneman, P. Slovic, and A. Tversky, 463–489. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Pres.
Spiegelhalter, D., M. Pearson, and I. Short. 2011. Visualizing uncertainty about the future. Science 333(6048): 1393–1400.
Stevens-Simon, C., et al. 1997. The effect of monetary incentives and peer support groups on repeat adolescent pregnancies: a randomized trial of the dollar-a-day program. JAMA 277: 977–982.
Studdert, D.M., M.M. Mello, W.M. Sage, C.M. DesRoches, J. Peugh, K. Zapert, et al. 2005. Defensive medicine among high-risk specialist physicians in a volatile malpractice environment. Journal of the American Medical Association 293: 2609–2617.
Sunstein, C.R. 2005. Laws of fear: beyond the precautionary principle. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.
Sunstein, C.R. 2013. The Storrs lectures: behavioral economics and paternalism. Yale Law Journal 122(7): 1826–1899.
Sunstein, C.R. 2014. Why nudge: the politics of libertarian paternalism. New Haven, NJ: Yale University Press.
Thaler, R.H. 1991. Quasi rational economics. New York: Russell Sage.
Thaler, R.H., and C.R. Sunstein. 2003. Libertarian paternalism. American Economic Review 93(2): 175–179.
Thaler, R.H., and C.R. Sunstein. 2008. Nudge: improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Till, C. 2013. Risk literacy: first steps in primary school. In eds. K. Makar, B. de Sousa & R. Gould, Sustainability in statistics education. Proceedings of the Ninth International Conference on Teaching Statistics (ICOTS9). Voorburg, Netherlands: International Statistical Institute.
Trout, J.D. 2005. Paternalism and cognitive ibias. Law and Philosophy 24: 393–434.
Tversky, A., and D. Kahneman. 1980. Causal schemata in judgments under uncertainty. In Progress in social psychology, vol. 1, ed. M. Fishbein, 49–72. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
Tversky, A., and D. Kahneman. 1981. The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science 211: 453–458. doi:10.1126/science.7455683.
Tversky, A., and D. Kahneman. 1986. Rational choice and the framing of decisions. The Journal of Business 59(4): S251–S278.
Wegwarth, O., L.M. Schwartz, S. Woloshin, W. Gaissmaier, and G. Gigerenzer. 2012. Do physicians understand cancer screening statistics? a national survey of primary care physicians in the United States. Annals of Internal Medicine 156: 340–349.
Welch, H.G. 2004. Should I be tested for cancer? Berkeley: University of California Press.
Woloshin, S., and L.M. Schwartz. 2012. How a charity oversells mammography. British Medical Journal 345: e5132. doi:10.1136/bmj.e5132.
Woloshin, S., L.M. Schwartz, and H.G. Welch. 2008. Know your chances: understanding health statistics. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Zhu, L., and G. Gigerenzer. 2006. Children can solve Bayesian problems: the role of representation in mental computation. Cognition 98: 287–308. doi:10.1016/j.cognition.2004.12.003.